Trade Liberalization And Land Use Changes: Explaining The Expansion Of Afforested Land In Chil
ruthsotomora22 de Mayo de 2014
3.745 Palabras (15 Páginas)710 Visitas
Trade Liberalization and Land Use Changes: Explaining the Expansion
of Afforested Land in Chile
Mario E. Niklitschek
Abstract: Trade policy reforms are expected to affect land use patterns in developing countries. Most of the
research has focused on explaining deforestation or the economic and environmental consequences of plantation
subsidies. This article examines the change in economic incentives resulting from trade reforms implemented in
Chile since the mid-1970s for land conversion to forest plantations. The removal of the log export ban and the
general import duties reduction affected forestry and land-competing agriculture both directly and indirectly
through the depreciation of the real exchange rate. Counterfactual roundwood relative prices were obtained by
estimating a generalized Leontief demand function for the domestic processing industry, and the “omega”
coefficient used in the analysis of agricultural trade reforms. The effects on the economic incentives for land
conversion were measured as the land rent changes under forestry and under competing agricultural use that
resulted from counterfactual policy scenarios. The results show the critical role of trade liberalization policies
in creating the necessary economic incentives for the private participation in the expansion of forest plantations
in Chile. The direct effect from the removal of the log export ban was estimated to be larger than the indirect
effect of the general import duty reductions. FOR. SCI. 53(3):385–394.
Keywords: log export ban, real exchange rate, roundwood relative prices, land rents, forest plantations
ECONOMY BROAD POLICIES, with effects on international
trade flows, property rights security, and the
general macroeconomic environment, have been
widely recognized to have a potentially important impact on
land use patterns in developing countries (Angelsen and
Kaimowitz 1999, Munasinghe 2001, Sedjo 2005). The concern
about tropical deforestation has led to an expansion of
research to model the conversion of forests to other land
uses (Kaimowitz et al. 1998). Significant attention has been
received by the possible environmental effects caused by
macroeconomic adjustment programs supported by international
lending institutions (Cruz and Repetto 1992, Sunderlin
et al. 2000). Establishing clear linkages among policy
instruments and forest cover losses has been elusive, however,
due to data limitations, particularly on land use
changes, requiring high levels of aggregation and few temporal
observations (Angelsen and Kaimowitz 1999) [1].
Despite the significant expansion of forest plantations in
a number of countries in the developed and developing
world, the policies behind this land use change have been
less scrutinized [2]. The general comparative advantages of
exotic plantations associated with a favorable location, resulting
from high biological productivity, accessibility to
markets, and terrain with low logging costs, can explain the
changes observed in the geographic distribution of the industry
and the composition of trade flows (Sedjo 1999). The
importance of trade policies among other general conditions,
including land tenure security, forest ownership, rural
finance, and the regulatory institutions, have been identified
as preconditions for the industry expansion (Laarman
1999). Since many of these effects are indirect and difficult
to trace, most of the quantitative analysis has focused on
sector-specific policies, particularly plantation cost sharing
incentives (Amacher et al. 1996, Hardie and Parks 1997,
Zhang and Flick 2001) [3].
Explaining the expansion of planted forests in Chile, an
area of more than 1.5 million hectares in a period of three
decades, offers an interesting analytical challenge. Disentangling
the different policy drivers, trade liberalization
versus sector policies, is difficult in the Chilean case because
the policy reforms were implemented almost simultaneously
in the mid-1970s. Many analysts have emphasized
the role of the 1974 Law Decree 701 (D.L. 701),
through which 75% of the afforestation expenses were
reimbursed to the landowner after certifying an adequate
rate of tree survival (Lara and Veblen 1991, Amacher et al.
1996, Toro and Gessel 1999). Even though other authors
have argued about the importance of trade policy reforms
and increasing property rights security, there has been no
attempt to estimate the contribution of the different factors
involved (Wisecarver 1988, Clapp 1995).
The analysis of the linkages of trade effects is important
for the evaluation of possible new programs in Chile, and
particularly for other countries that have sought to emulate
Chilean policies. Both the indirect effect resulting from the
general tariff reduction, particularly importable industrial
goods from an average tariff above 100%, and the removal
of the export log ban contributed to increase land rents in
Mario E. Niklitschek, Instituto de Manejo Forestal, Universidad Austral de Chile and Centro de Investigaciones, Casilla #567, Valdivia, Chile—(Phone)
56-63-221639; Fax: 56-63-221489; mniklits@uach.cl.
Acknowledgments: The author acknowledges partial financial support from the project “Trade liberalization, rural poverty and the environment” sponsored
by the World Bank and WWF. The author thanks Rosa Maria Alzamora for providing a spreadsheet with timber volume projections and the parameters on
the production system which allowed estimating land rents under different scenarios. The author also thanks Gonzalo Paredes and two anonymous reviewers
for helpful comments and suggestions. The opinions expressed are the author’s alone and do not necessarily correspond to those of sponsored institutions
or those with which he is affiliated.
Manuscript received September 6, 2006, accepted December 20, 2006 Copyright © 2007 by the Society of American Foresters
Forest Science 53(3) 2007 385
forestry. The intervention policies on food imports, which
had fluctuated widely between a focus on the protection of
urban real wages and their effect on the consumer price
index (CPI) and the support of farm income and domestic
production, also need to be considered in the analysis of
land use changes. Wheat is the main food crop produced in
rainfed areas and it competes for land with forest
plantations.
This article examines, under a mostly partial equilibrium
framework, land rent changes under different counterfactual
policy scenarios, including trade distortions and afforestation
subsidies. The methodology is based on the influential
work on the measurement of the incentive changes caused
by agricultural price and trade policies in developing countries
(Krueger 1992, Sadoulet and de Janvry 1995). The
conceptual framework for the analysis of the effect of
relative prices on land use changes borrows from the literature
on land use modeling under heterogeneous land quality
(Stavins and Jaffe 1990, Hardie and Parks 1997).
An important question addressed is how land rent associated
with different uses has changed as a result of trade
liberalization and sector-specific policies. More specifically,
the effect of across-the-board cuts of import duties,
including those on industrial products, the removal of the
log export ban, and the implementation of a band price
system for land-competing agricultural commodities, are
analyzed.
This article is organized as follows. The second section
briefly discusses the main policy changes and land use
patterns experienced by Chile since the import substitution
policies of the 1960s. In the third section, a simple Ricardian
model of land use changes under heterogeneous land
quality illustrates the effects of trade policy reforms on land
allocation. The methodology to measure the effect of policy
changes on relative prices and land rents is presented in the
fourth section. The remaining two sections present the results
and the conclusions.
Trade and Forest Policies in Chile: A Brief
Overview
The Chilean forest sector has had a remarkable performance
since the mid-1970s. The added value of the sector
has grown six-fold during the 1970–96 period, which is
three times higher than that of the total Chilean industry.
The sector productivity and employment have also experienced
a higher growth rate than those for the whole industry
(Katz et al. 2000). This expansion resulted in the transformation
of a protected import substitution activity, particularly
paper production for a small domestic market, into the
second largest export sector of the country. In 2003, it
accounted for 3.2% of gross domestic product (GDP) and
12.0% of total exports (Niklitschek and Gayoso 2005).
Both general (trade and land tenure security) and sectorspecific
policies (plantation cost sharing) had a role in
...