Estudio Economistas Franceses entre ellos Quesnai.
fgzz2002Documentos de Investigación25 de Abril de 2016
2.436 Palabras (10 Páginas)320 Visitas
STUDIES ON THE ORIGIN OF THE FRENCH
ECONOMISTS.
The French school of thinkers, which preceded and influenced
in so marked a manner the British originators of systematic
economics, and which in consideration of its recent
revival is rendered still more interesting, has hitherto been
judged in a most contradictory manner. "Their method and
fundamental ideas were negative," says Mr. Ingram, " resting,
as they did, essentially on the basis of the jtis naturae."" * On
the other hand, however, an authority no less respectable than
the late Professor Jevons declares that " the truth is with the
French school, and, the sooner we recognize the fact, the
better it will be for aU the world." f
It would be almost as difficult to reconcile these divergent
opinions as to arrive at a definite conclusion through the
known works of the phyBlocratic school. The followers of
Quesnay, jealous of their prestige, purposely concealed the
circumstances which led to the development of their science
and endowed it with its characteristic method. They declared
that about the year 1750 two ingenious men, Quesnay
and Goumay, had asked themselves "whether the i^ture of
things did not tend towards a science of political economy, and
what the principles of this science were." The task of specifying
this " nature of things " they, however, left to posterity,
unconscious that the superficial attire of their theories might
some time be mistaken for their essence.
The discovery of some manuscripts and letters of Quesnay,
the leader of the school, have rendered me doubtful as to
whether the historians of political economy have hitherto done
justice to the methods and intentions of the French economists.
I have elsewhere given copious extracts from the
manuscripts in question, % and am gratified now to have an
opportunity of exhibiting to an Anglo-American public the
results which my researches have yielded.
* A History of Political Economy, p. 67.
t Theory of Political Economy, p. xllll.
tJahrbVicher fnr Nationatdkonomie und StatistVc, N. F., Bd. xxl., August.
1890, "Zur BntsteLung der Physlokratie."
NOTES AND MEMORANDA 101
Two years ago. Professor A. Oncken, of Bern, re-edited the
works of Quesnay, affirming that the celebrated Tableau .Economique
was lost forever; and, moreover, he was unable to find
the articles " Hommes," ** Imp&t," and «InterSt de 1'Argent,"
which, Hke the well-known articles " Fermiers " and " Grains,"
Quesnay had written for the great JEncydop&die, but which he
had withdrawn when the latter work was forbidden by the government
in 1757. Professor Alfred Stern, of Zurich, who was
just preparing his Idfe of JUrabeau, expressed in a criticism
of Oncken's edition th« opinion that at least fragments of the
Tableau .Economique might be found among the papers of
Mirabeau the elder in the Archives Nationales at Paris. My
friend, the historian. Dr. Ludo Moritz Hartmann, of the University
of Vienna, drew my attention: to these observations;
and, when studying the history of economics at Paris, I found
the following documents: the original manuscript of the first
edition of the Tableau/ a second edition printed in three
copies; a series of letters of Quesnay to Mirabeau, explaining
his economical and political ideas; and a manuscript copy of
Cantillon's Eaaai sur la Nature du Commerce en GenSral. Encouraged
by these discoveries, I investigated the catalogue of
manuscripts in the Bibliothdque Nationale. There I found the
article " Homines." All my further researches have hitherto
proved fruitless; but I regard the new materials as a sufficient
justification for venturing a view different from the one commonly
accepted concerning the rise and methods of economics
in France.
The article " Hommes" is a statistical, historical, and theoretical
inquiry into the subject of population, its distribution
and its decreasing tendency, and into the causes of the latter
phenomenon. By a careful estimate, the author arrives at the
conclusion that an artificial policy had drained the people from
the country into the towns, by depriving them of their means
of subsistence. Fiscal extortion, occasioned by the military
policy of Louis XIV. and the favor bestowed upon the towns
in providing cheap bread, had caused great agricultural distress.
He shows that high prices accompanied the development
of agriculture in England, whereas low prices changed
the farmers of France into retailers and servants.
102 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
The stress laid upon English agriculture hy Quesnay induced
me to further investigations upon that point. I found
that the new methods of agriculture which were introduced
in England about the year 1730 hy Jethro Tull, Coke, and Viscount
Townsend, had produced the greatest sensation in
France. Duhamel du Monceau had systematized in 1750 the
"New Horsehoeing Husbandry" of Tull, and among the
French landed proprietors who availed themselves of these
innovations was the royal physician, Frangois Quesnay.* His
practical experience as an agriculturist gave him, it is natural
to suppose, a most vivid insight into the distress of
his neighbors, who from want of capital were unable to compete
with their wealthier rivals. At the same time, his theoretical
superiority over his predecessors was largely due to his
knowledge of English economics. The works of Locke and
Law had indeed influenced French economists like M61on and
Dupr6 de St. Maur.f But Cantillon's work was almost exclusively
the source of the physiocrat doctrine that the application
of capital to agriculture is the sole fountain of aU
wealth. Besides this last representative of English physiocracy,
which was to a good extent a development of mercantilism,!
Hiune's essays (translated in 1754 into French) gave a
proof of the futility of the reigning doctrine of the balance of
trade. But his theory of the creation of wealth hy labor, the
outcome of Sir William Petty's doctrine of its production hy
population, which Cantillon had accepted and Miraheau had
subsequently introduced into his Ami des Sommes (1756), was
refuted hy Quesnay. For in France capital was wanting, and
the increase of population seemed to be the consequence, and
not the cause of it. This divergence from the English doctrine
is therefore to be ascribed to his observations, as set
forth in his articles.
• His suocesBful experiments are described by Henry Fatullo, Essai ntr I'JnUlioration
des Terres, 1768, p. 77.
tin the Ephimerides du Citoyen for 1769, U., p. 67, Dupont de Nemours
regrets that the wise principles and truths found in the works of Culpeper,
Locke, Decker, Child, and especially Joslah Tucker, had not become known
earlier.
tin an article on Cantillon, in the forthcoming DlMonary o/PoUticaZ Eoonomy,
edited by Mr. B. H. Inglis Faigrave, I shall Introduce such proofs as will
indicate his English nationality.
NOTES AND MEMORANDA lOS
The inference he drew was a negative one indeed: that
all economic reform must commence with putting aside all
restrictioDS on the exportation of corn, which occasioned a
want of outlet and the ruin of the rural population. But
such a negative programme could not be prescribed as a
cure for another national distress,— the financial confusion.
Machault, the controller of finances of 1750, was unable to create
order, and after him Silhouette gave a fatal blow to public
credit. His successor in 1760 found the treasury empty.
One vingti^me was raised after another. The parliaments
protested in vain agamst government vexations, but, in spite
of the public calamity, were unable to recommend other measures
than " economy in the necessary expenses."
Plans of financial reform, especially concerning the taille,
had been modelled a long time before. The levelling and
centralizing tendency of Louis XIV.'s administrative policy
had given its stamp to most of them. One of the first of
tbese "systems," the dime royale of Vauban, exhibits the
advantages of a tenth upon all estates whatever. Other
...